After
trying to work out how big China’s bad debt problem might be, many people
still turn round and point to the country’s mammoth foreign exchange
reserves as its great get-out clause.
The
idea is seductive. On a deliberately gross calculation using the 20 per cent
non-performing loan rate found at China’s big banks in the late 1990s, total
bad debts would amount to Rmb21tn. A more sensible stab might put the level at
roughly half that, or Rmb10tn. These are painfully large numbers – but hang on,
China’s central bank has foreign exchange assets of $3.4tn, or Rmb20tn. Perfect
– what’s the problem?
It
is true that China dipped into its foreign exchange reserves in the late 1990s
to help recapitalise its banks before shifting their bad debts into specially
created bad banks.
However,
the government cannot now go to the same well to any large extent for a number
of reasons.
The
first is that any large scale spending of the reserves would amount to a
massive money-creation exercise by the central bank.
This
is to do with mechanics of how the reserves accumulated.
To
buy the dollars that China does not want sloshing around the economy, the
central bank creates Renminbi. However, in order to avoid a big money-printing
exercise it also issues treasury notes into the market to soak up – or
sterilise – the local currency created to buy the foreign currency.
The
vast majority of the foreign exchange reserve assets at the People’s Bank are
matched by Renminbi liabilities in China’s banks and other financial
institutions. If it tries to spend dollars without repaying these liabilities
it undoes its earlier sterlisation and prints money. If China wants to print
money to soak up its bad debts – and take the risks that come with this policy
– its foreign reserves are really irrelevant to that decision.
The
other problem with “spending” these reserves lies in the misconception that
they are an asset of the country – something like its retained profits from its
trade with the outside world.
China
has run a current account surplus of increasing size since the late 1990s. A
good chunk of this is money paid for goods and services sold – but another good
chunk is foreign direct investment. This is not money handed over by outsiders
never to be seen again. (Okay, so maybe it often seems like it is, but losing
to money to fraud and bad investments is not the point here…)
The
point is that the stock of net foreign direct investment represents a liability
of the country to outsiders – it is plant, equipment, streams of future profits
and so on that are owned by foreigners not by Chinese.
The
interesting thing about this is how big that stock has grown, especially in
recent years. Figures from the IMF (via Alicia Garcia-Herrero, chief economist
for emerging markets at BBVA) show that the stock of net FDI in China was
$1.66tn at the end of 2012. Over the five years from 2008, that stock grew by
$927bn.
Let’s
compare that to China’s foreign exchange “assets”. Between August 2008 and
March 2012, these grew by $1.56tn, according to Kevin Lai at Daiwa Capital
Markets in Hong Kong. In other words, China accumulated foreign exchange assets
not much faster than it accumulated FDI liabilities.
Mr
Lai makes a broader point about Asian foreign exchange reserves as a whole.
Betweeen 2008 and 2012, the total accumulated by China, India, Korea, Taiwan,
Hong Kong, Singapore, Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand and The Philippines almost
exactly matches the growth in the US federal Reserve’s balance sheet due to
quantitative easing. As he says, the correlation appears very high.
What
this suggests – and what is backed up by data from Hong Kong banks in
particular – is that along with FDI, China has recently drawn in a lot of cheap
credit from overseas. This also amounts to an external liability against the
forex assets.
The
final element is the effect of China’s strict capital controls and how they
might create another external liability for China – the retained profits of
foreign companies operating within its borders.
Western
companies report dividends from operations around the world, but as
Garcia-Herrero points out, just because they are reported, its doesn’t mean
that headquarters actually gets the cash – especially from China.
I
have not found any good estimations how big a stock of these retained profits
might be. But to grasp the issue, let’s think about Apple Inc. It famously has
some $50bn in cash trapped outside the US because it is unwilling to
pay the taxes on repatriating profits. However, some of this may be
trapped inside countries like China. The
question is how much?
China
is the only country, apart from the US, that accounted for more than 10 per
cent of Apple’s net sales last year – it made $22.8bn worth of sales there, up
from $2.8bn two years before. Its gross margins across the group were 44 per
cent, but its filings tell us nothing about what profits it made in China.
It
has reinvested some of the money it makes, accumulating what it calls
long-lived assets in China, which trebled last year to $7.3bn – more than the
long-lived assets it has in the US.
Apple
may escape capital controls by making more of its profits in Hong Kong than in
the mainland – we’d be very interested to see how those are split and what the
cash flows from China look like.
Video
News
No comments :
Post a Comment